Uploaded by Kalid Autocars

(04) Tugas Kel-2 dan 4

advertisement
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
DOI 10.1007/s12116-009-9044-1
Cores, Peripheries, and Contemporary
Political Economy
Erik Wibbels
Published online: 22 July 2009
# Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2009
Abstract This note underscores the need for more precise causal theories linking the
international division of labor, national economies, and public policies. To that end,
the author recommends two literatures upon which a revised dependency theory
might build, namely, those on economic geography and the political economy of
redistribution.
Keywords Economy . Capital . Dependency . Economic geography . Redistribution
There could not be a better time to revisit Cardoso and Falleto's seminal
contribution. As mortgage defaults in Los Vegas and Miami reverberate through
complex financial ties to the centers of global finance, a global depression looms.
And, as usual, this downturn will affect the developing world more severely. Thanks
to declining demand in core economies and retrenched investments by capital in
those same economies, developing economies will shrink more and suffer greater
volatility than their rich counterparts. If you think stock markets in New York and
Frankfurt have fallen sharply, you might consider looking at Russia, India, and
China where values have fallen twice as severely. So we see, yet again, that the
economies of developing nations are, in fact, dependent on their rich counterparts.
Whether or not that translates into dependency, as originally articulated in
Dependency and Development or as envisioned in these more recent contributions
is a whole different matter.
There is much to like in this collection of papers. I agree with several common
themes that appear across the contributions—that the manner of international
economic integration varies across countries, that reliance on external markets can be
consistent with advanced forms of production and development, that the operation of
international markets constrains choices, and that different forms of integration,
therefore, produce different kinds of constraints. I also agree with the widely argued
E. Wibbels (*)
Department of Political Science, Duke University, 306 Perkins Library, Durham, NC 27708, USA
e-mail: [email protected]
442
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
notion that there is some, albeit varying, scope for political choices. What I remain
puzzled by is how any of this relates to dependency, a concept that relies on a notion
of asymmetric political and economic power in the international system.
To my mind, the fundamental problem in the original dependency literature was a
failure to clearly define dependency. Yes, Dependency and Development provided a
great advance by linking international structure with national actors and institutions,
and its historically informed account of country experiences provides a compelling
view of dependency. At the same time, key concepts such as “enclaves” and
“unequal exchange” lacked the kind of rigor that would allow for the clear
articulation of causal arguments. In the absence of clear causal arguments,
convincing empirical tests of the theory's implications were elusive. To my mind,
it was this looseness of argument rather than any overwhelming evidence against the
spirit of the argument that contributed to the theory's declining status in the 1980s
and 1990s.
On this point, I find the contributors to this volume to have replicated the key
weakness of the original work. On the whole, the authors have diverse and vague
notions of what defines dependency. For Evans, it is reliance on a set of international
rules and institutions that are biased against developing nations. Kohli suggests that
dependency is created by political elites who pursue insufficiently nationalist and
state-led development. In his piece, Cardoso emphasizes the growing importance of
international financial capital and the ongoing reliance of developing countries on
technological innovations in the core. Conning and Robinson, though keenly aware
of the limitations of the original formulation of dependency, choose to emphasize the
importance of production in enclaves. Bruszt and Greskovits emphasize “diverse
international influences,” and the concept of dependency expands to include
countries that export human capital-intensive manufactured goods that historically
have been the purview of “core” economies.
In most of these cases, dependency is defined in terms too vague to know exactly
how it operates—the reader just cannot quite figure out what it is. It is also the case
that when reading across the pieces, it is hard to know what dependency is not, since
the key characteristics of dependency are so different from one contribution to the
next. The frequent reliance in these pages on typologies and types of development
does not help very much. The basic problem is that the political and economic
mechanisms through which dependency might work remain poorly articulated three
decades after the touchstone work was published.
I do not think a theory of dependency can be compelling unless it has reasonably
rigorous micro-foundations. By that I mean that both the systemic properties of the
international economy and the local manifestations of political power that
complement participation in the global economy should be linked to the selfinterest of the individuals who make up those economies. A micro-foundational
approach to dependency would work toward identifying the key actors—MNC
managers, international financiers, politicians, labor market participants, etc.—their
preferences, and the constraints under which they operate such that dependency
results. Well-developed micro-foundations would provide the basis for a systematic
exploration of the conditions under which markets and politics interact to produce
dysfunctional development outcomes. Such an approach would require the
methodical study of how international markets operate in everything from natural
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
443
resources to primary products to manufactured goods to financial instruments. Only
a reborn dependency that is rooted in an understanding of individual incentives and
reflective of a deep understanding of how specific markets operate will be able to
answer key questions: What kinds of markets are associated with dependency?
Agricultural markets? Natural resource markets? Financial markets? When and why
is foreign ownership a problem? Under what conditions do politicians have
incentives to align with foreign capital, domestic capital, labor, or some combination
thereof? What are the individual-level preferences of investors, labor market
participants, and the like that underpin the development of enclaves? In short, what
kinds of comparative advantage are most likely to produce dependency?
Economic Geography as Precursor to a Reinvigorated Dependency Theory
What makes the lack of micro-foundations particularly glaring in the contributions to
this volume is that there has been important work in economics and political science
over the last several decades that is of direct relevance to the intellectual agenda of
dependency theory. As Herman Schwartz (2007) noted in the pages of this journal
3 years ago, one of the most important would seem to be the “new economic
geography” inspired by Krugman's (1991) work on trade and geography. Motivated
by the simple observation that production is highly concentrated in space, Krugman
develops a simple model of economic cores and peripheries in which small initial
differences in endowments between two locations result in radically different
developmental outcomes. The key insight of the literature is that local economies
can be subject to increasing returns to scale. When increasing returns are present,
each additional investment attracts more investments, local job growth promotes
migration, and large markets beget larger markets. In such cases, the self-interest of
market participants can produce economic asymmetries that closely mirror those
between dependency theory's core, periphery, and semi-periphery.
In explaining when such dynamics are likely to be present, Krugman
emphasizes three factors: the size of the local market, transportation costs, and
externalities. As local market size increases, incentives mount for other producers
to locate nearby. When combined with positive externalities between firms—
externalities that emerge from labor market pooling, knowledge spillovers, or
input sharing—agglomeration effects redound to the benefit of the local economy
as productivity gains cumulate and growth explodes. Transportation costs work
in a parallel manner. As economies of scale mount, the incentives to produce in
any given location increase as its transportation networks improve—only thus
will initial investments be recouped by serving a broader market through trade.
This is true up to the point at which trade is nearly costless, in which case the
benefits of spillovers among firms are not mediated by proximity and the forces
for agglomeration begin to decline.
It is easy to see the relevance of Krugman's insights for the international
distribution of production, and subsequent work has emphasized the importance of
increasing returns for country specialization, the international division of labor, and
development. Related work provides a rigorous modeling of the conditions under
which domestically oriented big bangs produce development (Murphy et al. 1989)
444
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
and when production is likely to split off from cores, relocate to peripheries and
result in economic convergence between cores and peripheries (Venables 2007). The
key difference between these works of economic geography and dependency theory,
at least as articulated in the pieces for this volume, is that they have much more
precise accounts of the underlying dynamics that produce uneven development.
The economic geographers' account of cores and peripheries leaves little room for
politics. In Krugman's model, cores emerge for random reasons; initial advantages
are often minimal, but once increasing returns set in, cores and peripheries emerge
and only rarely do such dynamics break down. But even a cursory understanding of
the historical emergence of global capitalism suggests that today's international
distribution of wealth is the result of a deeply political process. It does not require a
great deal of imagination to marry Krugman's discussion of economic geography
with, for instance, Pomerantz's (2000) account of the nineteenth century divergence
of European wealth from the rest of the world. Carefully reconstructing price data
over the course of centuries, Pomerantz suggests that Western Europe became rich
thanks to the increasing returns that set in once the British discovered coal and
subsequently used their initial advantages to extract wealth from the rest of the world
through colonialism. In this account, the increasing returns that promoted early
British industrialization also provided the resources and incentives to politically
construct the first truly global capitalist economy.
Here, modern-day dependency theorists could bring much to the table by
analyzing the political causes and consequences of increasing returns. While
economists have done a nice job of identifying the key ingredients of increasing
returns, other social sciences have done a poor job of identifying the political
correlates, causes, or consequences of increasing returns.1 One promising avenue lies
with ongoing attempts to understand “path dependency,” a concept closely related to
that of increasing returns, but analyses of path dependency oftentimes lack general
mechanisms whereby political dynamics in the past inform the present and future
and, therefore, do not lend themselves easily to causal inference. By building more
rigorous analytical models of politics onto economic geography's intellectual
infrastructure, a reborn dependency theory might provide an empirically compelling
and analytically rigorous characterization of today's cores and peripheries. Such an
approach to the study of development, to my mind, would represent a stark departure
from the current conventional wisdom's emphasis on domestic institutions and
provide a reinvigorated dependency theory with some much-needed analytical rigor.
Economic Geography and Enclaves
One area where research on economic geography might speak very precisely to the
concerns of a reinvigorated dependency theory would be with regards to economic
enclaves. In this collection of essays, Cardoso revisits the concept and Conning and
Robinson focus on dependency qua foreign ownership. It is worth emphasizing that
The literature on the “developmental state” in East Asia probably comes closest to fitting the bill, but
with few exceptions (see Evans 1995 and Kohli 2004, for instance); it has been disinterested in
generalizing beyond outcomes in a single region.
1
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
445
a slightly different approach to enclaves, that inspired by Hirschman's (1958)
emphasis on natural resource production, has seen a boom over the last decade.
Broadly consistent with the instincts of dependency theory, research on the “resource
curse” suggests that oil wealth produces poor developmental and political outcomes.2 It is worth reflecting for a moment on how profound and heterodox the
implications of these finding are: under predictable circumstances, countries will
worsen developmental outcomes by relying on their comparative advantage and
engaging in trade.
The problem, however, is that the resource curse literature has suffered from
much the same problems as dependency theory—a lack of theoretical precision has
promoted the proliferation of hypotheses to explain the empirical findings. The main
problem is that the arguments provide limited insight into why natural resources
provided the foundation for broad-based economic growth in the USA, Canada,
Australia, and Norway (Wright 2001), but seem to produce enclave economies in
Nigeria, Venezuela, and Bolivia. In the former cases, democracy, development, and
natural resources have gone together. In the latter cases, enclave production has
promoted rent-seeking, clientelism, and waves of populism and authoritarianism. So
why are natural resources produced in enclaves, with all of their political and
economic dysfunctions in some cases while in others they seem consistent with
development and stable democracy?
Given that production of natural resources in enclaves is just a special case of
economic geography, it seems likely that the general theoretical insights from that
literature might help answer some of these questions. The simplest hypothesis that
would emerge from the economic geography literature is that the local income boom
associated with natural resource production will produce positive externalities as the
size of the local market increases. Where populations are smaller, less dense, and poorer,
local demand will be lower. The returns to natural resources will ensure extractive
investments, but the paucity of local demand will militate against positive spillovers to
other economic activities. Particularly when transportation costs are high, investments
will likely be concentrated only in the high return resource sector—the value to weight
ratio of other products will simply be too low to warrant producing them for outside
markets, and mineral production will not be associated with increasing returns.
It would not be hard to generalize these insights into an account of the
international political economy of natural resources that was consistent with diverse
national experiences with mineral wealth over the last several hundred years. Of
course, such an account would abstract away from important issues of international
power—the influence of international oil companies and their home governments in
developing international oil markets, for instance—but it is on these more political
aspects of economic geography that a reinvigorated dependency theory would have
much to add. Indeed, a renewed dependency theory might try to generalize these
insights from the economic geography of natural resource production to enclave
production more generally and develop systematic arguments as to how different
types of economic enclaves encourage politicians to pursue governance strategies
that vary in their use of political exclusion and coercion.
2
For a critical look at the resource curse literature, see the essays in Lederman and Maloney (2007).
446
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
Redistribution, Insurance, and Social Democracy in the Periphery
If the economic geography literature would provide a reinvigorated dependency
theory with more systematic tools for analyzing the international distribution of
production and income, two decades worth of research on redistribution would
provide it with more rigorous models of how and when politicians deploy the fiscal
powers of the state to mediate the domestic distributive effects of participating in
international markets. On this point, Cardoso's discussion of “globalized social
democracy” is quite optimistic, and the point is picked up in the Evans and Munck
contributions. The hope is that, as in Western Europe, participation in international
markets can be consistent with redistributive fiscal policy and domestic equity. That
hope conflicts with Dependency and Developments more pessimistic diagnosis,
which implied that dependent development implied coercive labor practices and
pronounced social inequities.
The optimistic tone does accord with the dominant account of the relationship
between trade, production, and social policy. That account suggests that social policy
emerges as a mean to compensate various labor market participants for the risks they
face and reflects the electoral power of the left. A key assumption of this story is that
the dynamics that underpin the emergence of social policy are common across the
developing and developed world. This assumption is most explicit in the work of
Lindert (2004), Rodrik (1998), and Adserá and Boix (2002), though a large body of
related literature implies as much.
Yet, such work fails to consider the fundamental importance of countries' diverse
positions in the global economy and how the changing dynamics of global
capitalism have altered the incentives for social provision through time. Evans
makes a similar point in his contribution to this volume when he suggests that the
contemporary international rules of the game militate against globalized social
democracy. My point is different, namely, that the nature of production and the
underlying features of the global economy that facilitated the rise of the welfare state
in the 1950s and 1960s in Europe are wholly gone. Indeed, the literature on
redistribution and insurance suggests that individuals' preferences for redistribution
and social insurance are a function of their position in the income distribution and
their exposure to risk (Moene and Wallerstein 2001), and related research (built
largely on the experience of the OECD) emphasizes the importance of electoral
systems and collective wage bargaining for fiscal policy and distributive outcomes.
While these insights are not directly related to economic openness, it is the case that
the operation of the global economy has important implications for national income
and risk distributions.
Post-war Europe benefited from an ideal set of conditions for the emergence of its
version of globalized social democracy. First, the European countries that developed
the large welfare states had comparative advantages in labor-intensive manufacturing. External demand for OECD goods in the 1950s was concentrated in metal
working and other sectors dominated by Fordist modes of production. This
comparative advantage produced large urban working classes that, along with some
smallholding rural sectors, provided the political foundations for the growth of the
welfare state. Thanks to their votes, parties of the left were consistently able to form
governments and implement redistributive policies. Second, manufacturing in the
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
447
OECD of the 1950s was a sector heavily dependent on trade and with high profit
margins. Given the centrality of trade, the key unions in most European countries
were in favor of trade. That these were high margin sectors meant that capital could
at least plausibly afford the tax burdens that funded the welfare state. Third and
finally, the most industrialized societies were small, trade-dependent ones where the
welfare state served to insure against the risks associated with heady levels of
external exposure. In these societies, coordinated wage bargaining, which was so
central to the insurance-laden systems of the OECD, emerged, in part, as an attempt
by cross-class coalitions to mediate the risks of international competition. As Mares
(2003) notes, organized employers played a central role in pushing for collective
bargaining and risk-sharing policies that provided the political backbone for the
insurance component of OECD welfare states. In short, Europe's position in the
global economy produced large, free-trading union movements that supported left
parties and redistributive spending while capital and labor coordinated risk-sharing
policies of social insurance to promote competitiveness and stability in open
economies.
The changed nature of the global economy in 2009 makes those ideal conditions
very difficult to replicate. The single most important difference between the 1950s
and the 2000s is the nature of manufacturing. While it is true that much
manufacturing has relocated to the developing world, technological innovations
allow for much higher levels of productivity with many fewer employees (Krugman
2000). Thus, while globalization has greatly increased global demand for
manufacturing, that demand can be satisfied with far fewer workers per unit
produced than in the heyday of European welfare state growth. One important
political implication is that manufacturing working classes, even in the most
industrialized developing nations, are far smaller than those in 1950s Norway, for
instance. Indeed, the most industrialized developing countries have manufacturing
workforces 25% smaller than Sweden or Germany in 1960.3 So while Chinese and
Malaysian working classes might be as free-trading as their counterparts 50 years
ago in much of Europe, they form a much smaller share of the working population
and have scarce the voice of their predecessors.
Second, while manufacturing today is a highly competitive, internationally
oriented sector much as it was in 1950s Europe, it is now typically a low-skill, lowvalue added sector with small profit margins. As a result, employers are much more
sensitive to the economic costs of social policy than they were in the 1950s in
Norway, and one is hard-pressed to find evidence of employers in the developing
world leading the charge on the benefits of wage coordination and social insurance.
It is also the case that the manufacturing production that has splintered off from the
OECD and relocated to the developing world has responded to agglomeration
economies. That means that it is the largest economies in the developing world that
are attracting the lion's share of industrial production—Brazil, Mexico, China, etc.—
whereas it was the smallest countries that became the most industrialized in the
OECD. In these large economies, the interests of workers and employers are more
heterogeneous and the high levels of political coordination that promoted the welfare
3
Data for developing countries is from the World Development Indicators 2008. The data for the West
European countries comes from Iversen and Cusack (2000) and is for the year1960.
448
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
state in Sweden are harder to pull off. When combined with the fact that capital
owners typically are much more mobile than 50 years ago, it is hard to imagine
employer–labor coordination playing the central role in the development of risksharing policies that provide the backbone for the European welfare states.
This all suggests that we need to pay attention to dependency theory's core
insight, namely, that there is an international division of labor and that division of
labor matters. To that I would add that the international division of labor is dynamic
and, therefore, the global economy that made the European welfare state possible in
the 1950s and 1960s is dead and gone. That said, the challenge for a new generation
of dependency theorists will be to take the micro-logic of the literature on insurance
and redistribution seriously, combine it with an understanding of how international
markets work, and produce predictions about redistributive politics that reflect
contemporary realities in the developing world. Inspired by the literature on risk and
redistribution (Moene and Wallerstein 2001; Iversen 2005), dependistas might revisit
Przeworski and Wallerstein's (1988) work on the dynamics of capital taxation in
contexts of class conflict and extend Mosley's (2003) work on the policy preferences
of international capital managers to examine how the network structure of
international economic competition conditions domestic conflicts over fiscal policy.
Conclusion
We are all just beginning to sort through the lessons of the current global
economic crisis. As bailout follows bailout in New York, London, and elsewhere,
it certainly seems to be the case that the state is structurally dependent on capital.
But at a more nuanced level, structural dependence has not precluded the failure
of even very big, powerful firms, and the location of national economies vis-à-vis
the global financial centers has had important implications for the depth of their
crises. To my mind, the most important contribution of Dependency and
Development was the way in which it unified analysis at the international level
with analysis of the domestic politics that sustained particular positions in the
international division of labor. Above, I have recommended two broad bodies of
literature in political economy—that on the new economic geography and that on
risk and redistribution—upon which a reinvigorated dependency theory might
rebuild. While the former literature provides insight into the emergence of cores and
peripheries within and between nations, the latter emphasizes the ways in which
taxing and spending policies help construct governing coalitions. Both literatures are
built on clear micro-foundations, something that the contributions to this volume
lack. Aligning those two literatures is no easy task, and it will be a serious challenge
to take the further step of linking their micro-logics to the broad macro-political and
macroeconomic outcomes that inspire thinkers in the dependency tradition. But the
payoffs could very well be high—together, they might just bring dependency theory
back to intellectual center stage at a time when much of the world is questioning its
dependency on the likes of AIG and Bank of America.
Acknowledgment Erik Wibbels would like to thank Rich Snyder and Patrick Heller for their critical
engagement with an earlier draft of these pages.
St Comp Int Dev (2009) 44:441–449
449
References
Adserá A, Boix C. Trade, democracy, and the size of the public sector: the political underpinnings of
openness. Int Organ. 2002;56:229–62.
Evans P. Embedded autonomy: states and industrial transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press;
1995.
Hirschman A. The strategy of economic development. New Haven: Yale University Press; 1958.
Iversen T. Capitalism, democracy, and welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2005.
Iversen, T, Cusak TR. 2000. The Causes of Welfare State Expansion: Deindustrialization or Globalization?
World Polit. 2000;52:313–49.
Kohli A. State-directed development: political power and industrialization in the global periphery. New
York: Cambridge University Press; 2004.
Krugman P. Geography and trade. Cambridge: MIT Press; 1991.
Krugman P. Technology, trade and factor prices. J Int Econ. 2000;50:51–71.
Lederman D, Maloney W, editors. Natural resources: neither curse nor destiny. Palo Alto: Stanford
University Press; 2007.
Lindert P. Growing public. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2004.
Mares IM. The sources of business interest in social insurance. World Polit. 2003;55:229–58.
Moene KO, Wallerstein M. Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. Am Polit Sci Rev.
2001;95:859–74.
Mosley L. Global capital and national governments. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2003.
Murphy K, Shleifer A, Vishny R. Income distribution, market size and industrialization. Q J Econ.
1989;3:537–64.
Pomerantz K. The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy.
Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2000.
Przeworski A, Wallerstein M. Structural dependence of the state on capital. Am Polit Sci Rev.
1988;83:11–29.
Rodrik D. Why do open economies have bigger governments? J Polit Econ. 1998;106:997–1032.
Schwartzm H. Dependency or institutions? Economic geography, causal mechanisms, and logic in the
understanding of development. Stud Comp Int Dev. 2007;42:115–35.
Venables A. Trade, location, and development: an overview of theory. In: Lederman and Maloney, editors.
Natural resources: neither curse nor destiny. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press; 2007;259–288.
Wright G. Resource based growth, then and now. Manuscript, Stanford University Department of
Economics; 2001.
Erik Wibbels is an Associate Professor of Political Science. His research focuses on development,
decentralized governance and other areas of comparative political economy.
Download